Beat the Press

Beat the press por Dean Baker

Beat the Press is Dean Baker's commentary on economic reporting. He is a Senior Economist at the Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR). To never miss a post, subscribe to a weekly email roundup of Beat the Press. Please also consider supporting the blog on Patreon.

I am not joking. A piece on All Things Considered carries the headline on NPR’s website “McDonald’s is losing customers to inflation.” The gist of the piece is that the economy is so bad that people can no longer afford to eat at McDonald’s. Now the company is being forced to lower its prices.

Incredibly, the piece never once mentions the company’s profits. They went from $11.18 billion in the year ending in December 2019, before the pandemic, to $14.69 billion in the year ending in March, an increase of more than 31 percent. That compares to an overall inflation rate of 21 percent over this period.

Rather than being a victim of inflation, McDonald’s was a cause of inflation. The company took advantage of the high demand and supply chain shortages to jack up its profit margins. Now, apparently competitive conditions in the fast-food industry are returning to something like their pre-pandemic state, and the company is being forced to accept more normal profit margins.

Instead of reporting this as a positive development for consumers, NPR presents it as yet one more bad economy story. It would be nice if we could get some reporting from the real world instead of having reporters who insist on writing pieces from the “bad economy storybook” even when they have no connection to reality.

I am not joking. A piece on All Things Considered carries the headline on NPR’s website “McDonald’s is losing customers to inflation.” The gist of the piece is that the economy is so bad that people can no longer afford to eat at McDonald’s. Now the company is being forced to lower its prices.

Incredibly, the piece never once mentions the company’s profits. They went from $11.18 billion in the year ending in December 2019, before the pandemic, to $14.69 billion in the year ending in March, an increase of more than 31 percent. That compares to an overall inflation rate of 21 percent over this period.

Rather than being a victim of inflation, McDonald’s was a cause of inflation. The company took advantage of the high demand and supply chain shortages to jack up its profit margins. Now, apparently competitive conditions in the fast-food industry are returning to something like their pre-pandemic state, and the company is being forced to accept more normal profit margins.

Instead of reporting this as a positive development for consumers, NPR presents it as yet one more bad economy story. It would be nice if we could get some reporting from the real world instead of having reporters who insist on writing pieces from the “bad economy storybook” even when they have no connection to reality.

Economists go on endless diatribes against tariffs and quotas as costly policies that raise prices to consumers and slow economic growth. There is considerable truth to this story, even if economists and politicians often exaggerate their case to push favored policies. While virtually all economists will go to their graves touting the evils of protectionism they almost all ignore the most costly forms of protectionism: government-granted patent and copyright monopolies.

Most tariffs raise the price of the protected items by somewhere in the range of 10–25 percent. By contrast, patent and copyright monopolies often raise the price of protected items by 1000 percent or even 10,000 percent. Many high-priced drugs that enjoy patent monopolies or related protections can sell for tens of thousands of dollars. Their generic versions might sell for $30 or $40 a prescription.  

There is a similar story for copyrights. Items that could be transferred at near zero cost over the Internet can instead sell for hundreds or even thousands of dollars. This is most evident with costly software, but also true for recorded music and video material, video games, and a variety of other material subject to copyright protections.

There is a clear rationale for patent and copyright monopolies, these monopolies provide an incentive for innovation and creative work. But every type of protectionism has a rationale. Having a rationale doesn’t prevent a trade tariff or quota from being a protectionist policy.

The point here is that these government-granted monopolies are huge interventions in the market. They are arguably justified, but it is close to nuts just to assert they are the free market. (Alternative mechanisms are discussed here and in chapter 5 of Rigged [it’s free]).

It is understandable that people on the right, who generally support policies that redistribute income upward, would try to hide patent and copyright monopolies as just the natural working of the market. It is absolutely mindboggling that many on the left also perpetuate this blatant misrepresentation of reality.

Anyhow, let’s get the playing field set. Granting these monopolies is a choice by governments, they can set different policies. In the case of Artificial Intelligence (AI), the New York Times reports that it seems as though China is rapidly catching up, and possibly even taking the lead, by pursuing open-source policies rather than relying on patents, copyrights, and related protection.

The idea of open-source with reference to AI is that all the coding is freely available to anyone to review and build upon. Understandably, this could be a more effective way to advance the technology since breakthroughs could quickly be built upon by others working in the same area. Also, researchers could learn from failures as well and avoid pursuing similar dead-ends. (This would be a great approach to drug or vaccine development.)

The other obvious development is that the finished product is very cheap. The developer may seek to recover costs by charging servicing fees and/or relying on direct government support. Either way, end users will not be prevented from being able to take advantage of a useful product by its high price.

Anyhow, given all the hype in the business world around AI it would certainly be ironic if Chinese firms surged past their leading U.S. competitors because they relied on an open-source process whereas our firms relied on old-fashioned protectionism. Who knows, maybe even the “free trader” economists would notice one day.  

Economists go on endless diatribes against tariffs and quotas as costly policies that raise prices to consumers and slow economic growth. There is considerable truth to this story, even if economists and politicians often exaggerate their case to push favored policies. While virtually all economists will go to their graves touting the evils of protectionism they almost all ignore the most costly forms of protectionism: government-granted patent and copyright monopolies.

Most tariffs raise the price of the protected items by somewhere in the range of 10–25 percent. By contrast, patent and copyright monopolies often raise the price of protected items by 1000 percent or even 10,000 percent. Many high-priced drugs that enjoy patent monopolies or related protections can sell for tens of thousands of dollars. Their generic versions might sell for $30 or $40 a prescription.  

There is a similar story for copyrights. Items that could be transferred at near zero cost over the Internet can instead sell for hundreds or even thousands of dollars. This is most evident with costly software, but also true for recorded music and video material, video games, and a variety of other material subject to copyright protections.

There is a clear rationale for patent and copyright monopolies, these monopolies provide an incentive for innovation and creative work. But every type of protectionism has a rationale. Having a rationale doesn’t prevent a trade tariff or quota from being a protectionist policy.

The point here is that these government-granted monopolies are huge interventions in the market. They are arguably justified, but it is close to nuts just to assert they are the free market. (Alternative mechanisms are discussed here and in chapter 5 of Rigged [it’s free]).

It is understandable that people on the right, who generally support policies that redistribute income upward, would try to hide patent and copyright monopolies as just the natural working of the market. It is absolutely mindboggling that many on the left also perpetuate this blatant misrepresentation of reality.

Anyhow, let’s get the playing field set. Granting these monopolies is a choice by governments, they can set different policies. In the case of Artificial Intelligence (AI), the New York Times reports that it seems as though China is rapidly catching up, and possibly even taking the lead, by pursuing open-source policies rather than relying on patents, copyrights, and related protection.

The idea of open-source with reference to AI is that all the coding is freely available to anyone to review and build upon. Understandably, this could be a more effective way to advance the technology since breakthroughs could quickly be built upon by others working in the same area. Also, researchers could learn from failures as well and avoid pursuing similar dead-ends. (This would be a great approach to drug or vaccine development.)

The other obvious development is that the finished product is very cheap. The developer may seek to recover costs by charging servicing fees and/or relying on direct government support. Either way, end users will not be prevented from being able to take advantage of a useful product by its high price.

Anyhow, given all the hype in the business world around AI it would certainly be ironic if Chinese firms surged past their leading U.S. competitors because they relied on an open-source process whereas our firms relied on old-fashioned protectionism. Who knows, maybe even the “free trader” economists would notice one day.  

Seriously, they probably don’t want readers to walk away with that impression, but that is the implication of the piece they did complaining about people working multiple jobs. The piece told readers:

“A record number of Americans worked more than one job last year, and multiple-job holders as a percentage of the total workforce recently matched the highest share since 2019. That was largely driven by women, who worked multiple jobs at the highest rate since the 1990s in December.”

Multiple job holding is not necessarily a sign of a bad labor market. The share of multiple jobholders peaked before the pandemic in 2019 when the recovery was at its peak. Furthermore, as the article itself notes, people might hold multiple jobs because of increased opportunities, not economic hardship.

For example, 36 percent of multiple job holders report that they do telework. The opportunity to do telework was much more limited before the pandemic. Likely, many of these multiple job holders would not be working at multiple jobs if they didn’t have the opportunity to work from home.

The piece does find people who report experiencing economic hardship, but in an economy with 160 million workers, there will also be millions experiencing economic hardship. For some reason, Bloomberg has chosen to seek out these people out and highlight their situations.

By contrast, millions of people work in hotels and restaurants. Their average hourly wage has risen by almost 31 percent since the start of the pandemic in 2020, far above the 21 percent increase in prices over this period. Surely many of these people are doing considerably better now than in 2020.

For some reason, Bloomberg and most of the rest of the media have decided to ignore these and other moderate-income workers who have seen their situation substantially improve as a result of the strong labor market of the last two and half years.   

Seriously, they probably don’t want readers to walk away with that impression, but that is the implication of the piece they did complaining about people working multiple jobs. The piece told readers:

“A record number of Americans worked more than one job last year, and multiple-job holders as a percentage of the total workforce recently matched the highest share since 2019. That was largely driven by women, who worked multiple jobs at the highest rate since the 1990s in December.”

Multiple job holding is not necessarily a sign of a bad labor market. The share of multiple jobholders peaked before the pandemic in 2019 when the recovery was at its peak. Furthermore, as the article itself notes, people might hold multiple jobs because of increased opportunities, not economic hardship.

For example, 36 percent of multiple job holders report that they do telework. The opportunity to do telework was much more limited before the pandemic. Likely, many of these multiple job holders would not be working at multiple jobs if they didn’t have the opportunity to work from home.

The piece does find people who report experiencing economic hardship, but in an economy with 160 million workers, there will also be millions experiencing economic hardship. For some reason, Bloomberg has chosen to seek out these people out and highlight their situations.

By contrast, millions of people work in hotels and restaurants. Their average hourly wage has risen by almost 31 percent since the start of the pandemic in 2020, far above the 21 percent increase in prices over this period. Surely many of these people are doing considerably better now than in 2020.

For some reason, Bloomberg and most of the rest of the media have decided to ignore these and other moderate-income workers who have seen their situation substantially improve as a result of the strong labor market of the last two and half years.   

Marketplace radio had a piece on the drop in the saving rate reported for the month of June that committed two major sins. One was ungodly ignorant but inconsequential. The other was more understandable, but far more important.

Starting with the ungodly ignorant one, Marketplace quoted Merrill Reynolds Jr., a faculty member of the banking school at Southern Methodist University,  saying people who can afford to are investing rather than saving.

“’It might be real estate, might be stocks,’ he said. ‘Potentially, the stock market or other types of investments out there have certainly been more lucrative — provided you know what you’re doing.’”

This is ungodly ignorant because buying real estate or stocks are both forms of savings. Saving is defined as disposable income (income left over after taxes) minus spending on current consumption. Any money that is not spent on current consumption is by definition saved.

That means that the money that someone might spend on stocks or real estate still counts as savings in the GDP accounts. Back in the old days when I taught intro macro I used to give all the things that counted as saving in the GDP accounts. In addition to buying stocks and real estate, if I bought foreign currency or Bitcoin that would also be forms of savings. If I took my paycheck, cashed it at the bank, and then burned the money, that would still be savings. If I didn’t spend it on current consumption (a newly produced consumption good or service) it is savings.

This matters in this context because if people are using their income to buy stock, real estate, or other financial assets, they are still saving. That cannot explain a drop in the saving rate.

Okay, that is the ungodly ignorant one, now for the more important one. The point of the piece is that the reported saving rate of 3.4 percent is extraordinarily low (see line 35 in the Table). This is true, it was typically in the range of 5.5 to 6.5 percent before the pandemic. But, there is a big problem with the reported saving rate.

This is a somewhat nerdy technical issue, so get your boredom protection shield out. Remember savings is defined as the difference between disposable income and spending on current consumption. There is a huge problem in how these are measured.

In recent quarters there has been a huge gap in measuring GDP on the output side and the income side. This is called the “statistical discrepancy” in the GDP accounts. In the most recent quarter, it was equal to 2.3 percent of GDP (line  34 in the table).

Keep in mind that GDP measured on the output side (consumption, investment, government and net exports) is by definition equal to GDP on the income side (wages and benefits, profits, interest and rents). Think of it like counting bales of hay starting from the left as opposed to starting from the right. There are a certain number of bales in the barn and the number should not be affected by which side you start counting from.

This is the story with GDP. It shouldn’t matter whether we measure it from the output side or the income side, we should come up with the same number. However, in an economy that is nearly $30 trillion, they will never come out exactly equal.

That is ordinarily not a big deal, but the gap has become very large in recent quarters, and it shows output side GDP to be far larger than income side GDP. This matters a lot for the saving rate, which can be easily shown.

First, I don’t know which side is closer to the mark, but it doesn’t matter for this point. Let’s say that the output measure is mostly right, and that income is around 2.3 percent higher than is currently reported.

There are some steps to get from national income to disposable personal income, but any increase in national income is likely to translate pretty closely into an increase in personal income, and since we know taxes pretty well already, it will translate into an increase in disposable income.

Suppose true disposable income is 2.3 percent higher than is now reported. Since consumption has not changed, the true saving rate would be roughly 2.3 percentage points higher than the reported saving rate. That would put it around 5.7 percent, close to the pre-pandemic average.

That’s the story where the output side measure is right, but let’s assume the income side measure is right. In that case, output is 2.3 percentage points lower than is now reported. That error could be anywhere, but consumption is 70 percent of GDP and the government part is pretty well measured, so as a first approximation we can probably assume that if output side GDP is overstated by 2.3 percent, that consumption is overstated by 2.3 percent.

In this case, we get the same result. If the true amount of consumption spending is 2.3 percent below the reported amount, then the saving rate is 2.3 percentage points higher than is currently reported. We are again back to a saving rate of around 5.7 percent, near the pre-pandemic average.

In reality, further revisions to the GDP accounts will likely show the revised number to be somewhere in the middle, but for purposes of calculating the saving rate, it really doesn’t matter which is closer to the mark. Reducing the measured size of the statistical discrepancy will almost certainly lead to a higher measured saving rate that is close to the average in the years just before the pandemic.

In short, Marketplace Radio was trying to explain a problem that does not exist in the world. The drop in the saving rate is an artifact of the data, not something that actually exists.   

 

Marketplace radio had a piece on the drop in the saving rate reported for the month of June that committed two major sins. One was ungodly ignorant but inconsequential. The other was more understandable, but far more important.

Starting with the ungodly ignorant one, Marketplace quoted Merrill Reynolds Jr., a faculty member of the banking school at Southern Methodist University,  saying people who can afford to are investing rather than saving.

“’It might be real estate, might be stocks,’ he said. ‘Potentially, the stock market or other types of investments out there have certainly been more lucrative — provided you know what you’re doing.’”

This is ungodly ignorant because buying real estate or stocks are both forms of savings. Saving is defined as disposable income (income left over after taxes) minus spending on current consumption. Any money that is not spent on current consumption is by definition saved.

That means that the money that someone might spend on stocks or real estate still counts as savings in the GDP accounts. Back in the old days when I taught intro macro I used to give all the things that counted as saving in the GDP accounts. In addition to buying stocks and real estate, if I bought foreign currency or Bitcoin that would also be forms of savings. If I took my paycheck, cashed it at the bank, and then burned the money, that would still be savings. If I didn’t spend it on current consumption (a newly produced consumption good or service) it is savings.

This matters in this context because if people are using their income to buy stock, real estate, or other financial assets, they are still saving. That cannot explain a drop in the saving rate.

Okay, that is the ungodly ignorant one, now for the more important one. The point of the piece is that the reported saving rate of 3.4 percent is extraordinarily low (see line 35 in the Table). This is true, it was typically in the range of 5.5 to 6.5 percent before the pandemic. But, there is a big problem with the reported saving rate.

This is a somewhat nerdy technical issue, so get your boredom protection shield out. Remember savings is defined as the difference between disposable income and spending on current consumption. There is a huge problem in how these are measured.

In recent quarters there has been a huge gap in measuring GDP on the output side and the income side. This is called the “statistical discrepancy” in the GDP accounts. In the most recent quarter, it was equal to 2.3 percent of GDP (line  34 in the table).

Keep in mind that GDP measured on the output side (consumption, investment, government and net exports) is by definition equal to GDP on the income side (wages and benefits, profits, interest and rents). Think of it like counting bales of hay starting from the left as opposed to starting from the right. There are a certain number of bales in the barn and the number should not be affected by which side you start counting from.

This is the story with GDP. It shouldn’t matter whether we measure it from the output side or the income side, we should come up with the same number. However, in an economy that is nearly $30 trillion, they will never come out exactly equal.

That is ordinarily not a big deal, but the gap has become very large in recent quarters, and it shows output side GDP to be far larger than income side GDP. This matters a lot for the saving rate, which can be easily shown.

First, I don’t know which side is closer to the mark, but it doesn’t matter for this point. Let’s say that the output measure is mostly right, and that income is around 2.3 percent higher than is currently reported.

There are some steps to get from national income to disposable personal income, but any increase in national income is likely to translate pretty closely into an increase in personal income, and since we know taxes pretty well already, it will translate into an increase in disposable income.

Suppose true disposable income is 2.3 percent higher than is now reported. Since consumption has not changed, the true saving rate would be roughly 2.3 percentage points higher than the reported saving rate. That would put it around 5.7 percent, close to the pre-pandemic average.

That’s the story where the output side measure is right, but let’s assume the income side measure is right. In that case, output is 2.3 percentage points lower than is now reported. That error could be anywhere, but consumption is 70 percent of GDP and the government part is pretty well measured, so as a first approximation we can probably assume that if output side GDP is overstated by 2.3 percent, that consumption is overstated by 2.3 percent.

In this case, we get the same result. If the true amount of consumption spending is 2.3 percent below the reported amount, then the saving rate is 2.3 percentage points higher than is currently reported. We are again back to a saving rate of around 5.7 percent, near the pre-pandemic average.

In reality, further revisions to the GDP accounts will likely show the revised number to be somewhere in the middle, but for purposes of calculating the saving rate, it really doesn’t matter which is closer to the mark. Reducing the measured size of the statistical discrepancy will almost certainly lead to a higher measured saving rate that is close to the average in the years just before the pandemic.

In short, Marketplace Radio was trying to explain a problem that does not exist in the world. The drop in the saving rate is an artifact of the data, not something that actually exists.   

 

I don’t have the answer to that question, but if I was CNN’s pollster I would be concerned. They just did a poll on households’ financial situation and the responses they got are clearly out-of-line with a number of different independent data sources.

For example, the poll found that 35 percent of people said that they had to take on extra work to make ends meet. But the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ survey of households finds that just 5.1 percent of workers report being multiple job holders, the same as the year-round average for 2019 before the pandemic.

 

Furthermore, 36 percent of the people who report that they have multiple jobs also say they do telework. This indicates that many of the multiple jobholders have a second job because they have increased opportunities, not just out of necessity.

Unfortunately, this is not the only item in CNN’s poll that seems radically out of line with independent data sources. The poll finds that 69 percent of people cut back on extras and entertainment. But, this contradicts Commerce Department data showing that real (inflation-adjusted) spending at restaurants is up by 1.7 percent from last year and 10.7 percent from the fourth quarter of 2019 before the pandemic. Real spending at fast-food restaurants is up 2.1 percent from last year and 11.8 percent from before the pandemic.

Real spending at hotels and motels is up by 9.9 percent from last year and 7.4 percent from before the pandemic. Real spending at spectator sports is up 9.9 percent from before the pandemic, although it’s down 7.0 percent from last year. (There was a big jump in the second quarter of 2023 for some reason.) Spending on air travel is up 9.0 percent from last year and 49.5 percent from before the pandemic. This also fits travel data from the Transportation Security Authority (TSA) showing record numbers of people going through security checks.

Purchases of sports equipment and recreational vehicles is up 26.7 percent from before the pandemic, although down by 2.2 percent from last year. Spending on video and audio equipment is up by 50.2 percent from before the pandemic and 5.5 percent from last year.

These are areas that we might think of as “extras,” but in every case real spending is well above the pre-pandemic level and in almost every case considerably above the year-ago level. If the 69 percent of the people in the CNN poll who report cutting back are accurately describing their behavior, then the other 31 percent must be spending like crazy.

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis and author’s calculations.

CNN also reports that 41 percent of respondents say they have cut back their driving. By contrast, the Commerce Department data show that gas consumption is up by 1.8 percent from before the pandemic, although it is down 0.5 percent from last year. Before making too much of that year-over-year drop off consider that there were 1.1 million electric vehicles sold last year, 2.0 million hybrids, and 0.2 plugin hybrids. This means we could have seen more cars on the road with less gas being used, which is basically what the American Automobile Association (AAA) found in its surveys.

We know that we have huge a problem with inequality in this country, but that doesn’t seem to offer much of an explanation. After all, do we think it’s plausible that the rich suddenly started eating much more fast food since the pandemic and driving everywhere around the country?

We know that jobs are relatively plentiful. The unemployment rate has risen somewhat in the last 14 months, but it is still unusually low at 4.1 percent. Furthermore, wage increases at the bottom end of the wage distribution have far outpaced inflation, so this is not consistent with low-income workers feeling especially stressed right now.  

To be clear, we know that tens of millions of people are struggling to make ends meet and that many are falling short, going hungry and/or losing housing. But this was the story before the pandemic also, when most people were positive about the economy.

In short, the data on people’s spending patterns does not seem consistent with what people are telling CNN in its poll. I’ll let CNN figure out why there would be this discrepancy, but I am inclined to trust the data on retail sales, which come from a variety of different sources, and are confirmed by independent sources like TSA and AAA, than the answers CNN got in its poll.

I don’t have the answer to that question, but if I was CNN’s pollster I would be concerned. They just did a poll on households’ financial situation and the responses they got are clearly out-of-line with a number of different independent data sources.

For example, the poll found that 35 percent of people said that they had to take on extra work to make ends meet. But the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ survey of households finds that just 5.1 percent of workers report being multiple job holders, the same as the year-round average for 2019 before the pandemic.

 

Furthermore, 36 percent of the people who report that they have multiple jobs also say they do telework. This indicates that many of the multiple jobholders have a second job because they have increased opportunities, not just out of necessity.

Unfortunately, this is not the only item in CNN’s poll that seems radically out of line with independent data sources. The poll finds that 69 percent of people cut back on extras and entertainment. But, this contradicts Commerce Department data showing that real (inflation-adjusted) spending at restaurants is up by 1.7 percent from last year and 10.7 percent from the fourth quarter of 2019 before the pandemic. Real spending at fast-food restaurants is up 2.1 percent from last year and 11.8 percent from before the pandemic.

Real spending at hotels and motels is up by 9.9 percent from last year and 7.4 percent from before the pandemic. Real spending at spectator sports is up 9.9 percent from before the pandemic, although it’s down 7.0 percent from last year. (There was a big jump in the second quarter of 2023 for some reason.) Spending on air travel is up 9.0 percent from last year and 49.5 percent from before the pandemic. This also fits travel data from the Transportation Security Authority (TSA) showing record numbers of people going through security checks.

Purchases of sports equipment and recreational vehicles is up 26.7 percent from before the pandemic, although down by 2.2 percent from last year. Spending on video and audio equipment is up by 50.2 percent from before the pandemic and 5.5 percent from last year.

These are areas that we might think of as “extras,” but in every case real spending is well above the pre-pandemic level and in almost every case considerably above the year-ago level. If the 69 percent of the people in the CNN poll who report cutting back are accurately describing their behavior, then the other 31 percent must be spending like crazy.

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis and author’s calculations.

CNN also reports that 41 percent of respondents say they have cut back their driving. By contrast, the Commerce Department data show that gas consumption is up by 1.8 percent from before the pandemic, although it is down 0.5 percent from last year. Before making too much of that year-over-year drop off consider that there were 1.1 million electric vehicles sold last year, 2.0 million hybrids, and 0.2 plugin hybrids. This means we could have seen more cars on the road with less gas being used, which is basically what the American Automobile Association (AAA) found in its surveys.

We know that we have huge a problem with inequality in this country, but that doesn’t seem to offer much of an explanation. After all, do we think it’s plausible that the rich suddenly started eating much more fast food since the pandemic and driving everywhere around the country?

We know that jobs are relatively plentiful. The unemployment rate has risen somewhat in the last 14 months, but it is still unusually low at 4.1 percent. Furthermore, wage increases at the bottom end of the wage distribution have far outpaced inflation, so this is not consistent with low-income workers feeling especially stressed right now.  

To be clear, we know that tens of millions of people are struggling to make ends meet and that many are falling short, going hungry and/or losing housing. But this was the story before the pandemic also, when most people were positive about the economy.

In short, the data on people’s spending patterns does not seem consistent with what people are telling CNN in its poll. I’ll let CNN figure out why there would be this discrepancy, but I am inclined to trust the data on retail sales, which come from a variety of different sources, and are confirmed by independent sources like TSA and AAA, than the answers CNN got in its poll.

This really is kind of mind-boggling. It had a nice piece pointing out that it has now been 15 years since the last hike in the federal minimum wage. This is the longest stretch since the federal minimum wage was first established in 1938. The real value of the minimum wage has been allowed to fall to its 1949 level. These points are well-taken as is its noting of research showing that higher minimum wages do not cost jobs.

But when it came to an explanation as to why the minimum wage has not been raised it told listeners:

“But the idea keeps going nowhere. Why? The short answer is congressional gridlock.”

Huh? Almost every Democrat in Congress has voted for higher minimum wages over this period. Almost every Republican has voted against minimum wage hikes. There is a pretty clear story here, the minimum wage has not been increased because Republicans oppose a higher minimum wage.

Is there some reason Marketplace Radio couldn’t be honest with its listeners? The Republicans can presumably defend their position, but why is the show hiding it? Democrats support a higher minimum wage, Republicans oppose one. When it comes to explaining why it hasn’t been raised for 15 years, it is that simple.

This really is kind of mind-boggling. It had a nice piece pointing out that it has now been 15 years since the last hike in the federal minimum wage. This is the longest stretch since the federal minimum wage was first established in 1938. The real value of the minimum wage has been allowed to fall to its 1949 level. These points are well-taken as is its noting of research showing that higher minimum wages do not cost jobs.

But when it came to an explanation as to why the minimum wage has not been raised it told listeners:

“But the idea keeps going nowhere. Why? The short answer is congressional gridlock.”

Huh? Almost every Democrat in Congress has voted for higher minimum wages over this period. Almost every Republican has voted against minimum wage hikes. There is a pretty clear story here, the minimum wage has not been increased because Republicans oppose a higher minimum wage.

Is there some reason Marketplace Radio couldn’t be honest with its listeners? The Republicans can presumably defend their position, but why is the show hiding it? Democrats support a higher minimum wage, Republicans oppose one. When it comes to explaining why it hasn’t been raised for 15 years, it is that simple.

A Tribute to President Biden

I’m not generally one to get teary-eyed over politicians. They mostly spend their careers trying to appease people with money and power. That’s how you get ahead in American politics. (There are exceptions, most obviously people like Bernie Sanders and Elizabeth Warren.) But they also are the ones who at the end of the day make policy and these policies make a huge difference in the lives of real people, for better or worse.

And once you get to the very top, it is hard to let go. President Biden really deserves our thanks for recognizing that he could best serve the party, the country, and the world by passing the torch.

Biden has much to show for his term in office to date. On the domestic side, he was the most impactful president in more than half a century. First and foremost, he pushed through his big recovery package just after taking office.

Job growth had slowed to a crawl in the last three months of the Trump administration. It would have taken five and half years to get back the lost jobs at the pace the economy was creating them from November of 2020 to January of 2021. Instead, we got the jobs back in a year and half under Biden.

The rapid job growth quickly got us back to full employment, with the unemployment rate reaching 4.0 percent by the end of the year. It fell further in 2022 and remained very low through 2023, although it has crept up modestly in recent months.

We saw the predicted benefits of full employment. The labor market improved most for the most disadvantaged groups in the labor market. Blacks, Black teens, and Hispanics all saw their unemployment rates fall to record lows.

The wage growth was most rapid at the lower end of the wage ladder, reversing the pattern of the last forty-five years. The gap in median wages between white workers and Black workers fell to the lowest level on record.

The strong labor market gave workers unprecedented ability to leave jobs they didn’t like. They could leave boring and dangerous jobs, or ones with few opportunities for advancement, and seek out better ones. As a result, workers reported the highest level of job satisfaction on record.    

It’s also important to remind people that Biden really does deserve credit for the recovery package. He pushed it through Congress with only a couple votes to spare in the House and no room in the Senate.

After getting the recovery package through, Biden managed to pass three major bills with long-term impact. First, he passed a bipartisan infrastructure bill, which allocated funding not just for traditional infrastructure, but also replacing lead pipes for drinking water, extended high-speed Internet access, and established a national charging station network for electric vehicles.

He then passed the CHIPS Act which appropriated money for research and provided subsidies for building cutting edge semiconductors in the United States. The case for reshoring manufacturing can be overstated, but it is important to ensure secure supplies of essential economic inputs, and semiconductors certainly fit in that category.

Most importantly, Biden got the Inflation Reduction Act (IRA) passed. This bill was primarily about kick-starting the green transition with subsidies for wind and solar energy, as well as electric vehicles.

While it is easy to say that the bill is inadequate given the size of the problem, the point is that it is a huge foot in the door. Going forward, it will not just be environmentalist-types pushing for money for the transition, it will be major businesses looking for profits. We can be fairly confident that, apart from a complete political catastrophe, we will see considerable pressure for further support for a green transition.

The IRA also included more funding for I.R.S. enforcement. This is a big deal since rich people were increasingly seeing taxes as optional. The I.R.S. now has cops on the beat to crack down on billionaire tax cheats.

Biden also pushed a pro-labor agenda, appointing people to the National Labor Relations Board who take seriously the responsibility to protect workers’ right to organize. He was also the first president ever to join a union picket line when he marched with UAW strikers last fall.

He also appointed people to the Federal Trade Commission and the Justice Department who take anti-trust policy seriously. Mergers and acquisitions that might have gone through unquestioned under prior administrations were scrutinized, and in some cases blocked.

We have seen a half-century of anti-labor policies and neglect of meaningful anti-trust enforcement. This cannot be reversed in a single four-year term, but Biden made a very good start.

I have written much on Biden’s record on domestic policy and will write more, but it was very impactful. He has much to show for three and half years in office with the barest congressional majority in the first two years and a split Congress in the second half of his term. He will be stepping down at the top of his game.

Getting back to Biden’s decision to step down, it is difficult to imagine how hard it is for these people to give up the power and status they have struggled for a lifetime to gain. To take a more pernicious example of a politician whose career in some ways paralleled Biden’s, Richard Nixon rose from a modest background to become vice-president, before narrowly losing the presidential race in 1960 to John F. Kennedy. He then lost a race for governor in California and seemed to declare the end of his political career, saying in an angry press conference “you won’t have Dick Nixon to kick around anymore.”

Remarkably, he came back to get the Republican nomination and then slip into the White House in 1968 in another close election. Being obsessed with power, he spied on his opponents and engaged in various types of illegal activity to contain opposition. (The current SCOTUS would probably say it was all legal.)

Anyhow, things began to unravel for Nixon when the Watergate break-in was uncovered and then people began to talk. The line got traced back to the White House and the key evidence was to be found on Nixon’s own tapes. When the Supreme Court ordered them released and the public saw them, it was clear that Nixon was in on the coverup from the beginning and everything he had said about the case was a lie.

In spite of this, Nixon was prepared to tough it out. The Republicans in Congress realized this was a disaster for the party. They sent a delegation of three senior senators to see Nixon, led by Barry Goldwater, the 1964 nominee and godfather of the modern conservative movement.

They told Nixon the score, trying politely to urge him to step down. Since Nixon’s impeachment in the House was already a foregone conclusion, he began to inquire about whether he could get the one-third of the Senate needed to keep him in office.

According to their account, Nixon turned to them and said something to the effect of “let’s see, I have you three” and then started to come up with other potential names. Goldwater shut this down by telling Nixon that he didn’t know that he could count on him. Nixon resigned the next day.

Anyhow, President Biden obviously cares far more about the country and the party, but the Nixon episode shows how hard it can be for people to step aside once they have attained the pinnacle of power. We really do owe him a big debt of gratitude.

I will add one more point to put this in context. Can anyone imagine Donald Trump doing the same thing?  

I’m not generally one to get teary-eyed over politicians. They mostly spend their careers trying to appease people with money and power. That’s how you get ahead in American politics. (There are exceptions, most obviously people like Bernie Sanders and Elizabeth Warren.) But they also are the ones who at the end of the day make policy and these policies make a huge difference in the lives of real people, for better or worse.

And once you get to the very top, it is hard to let go. President Biden really deserves our thanks for recognizing that he could best serve the party, the country, and the world by passing the torch.

Biden has much to show for his term in office to date. On the domestic side, he was the most impactful president in more than half a century. First and foremost, he pushed through his big recovery package just after taking office.

Job growth had slowed to a crawl in the last three months of the Trump administration. It would have taken five and half years to get back the lost jobs at the pace the economy was creating them from November of 2020 to January of 2021. Instead, we got the jobs back in a year and half under Biden.

The rapid job growth quickly got us back to full employment, with the unemployment rate reaching 4.0 percent by the end of the year. It fell further in 2022 and remained very low through 2023, although it has crept up modestly in recent months.

We saw the predicted benefits of full employment. The labor market improved most for the most disadvantaged groups in the labor market. Blacks, Black teens, and Hispanics all saw their unemployment rates fall to record lows.

The wage growth was most rapid at the lower end of the wage ladder, reversing the pattern of the last forty-five years. The gap in median wages between white workers and Black workers fell to the lowest level on record.

The strong labor market gave workers unprecedented ability to leave jobs they didn’t like. They could leave boring and dangerous jobs, or ones with few opportunities for advancement, and seek out better ones. As a result, workers reported the highest level of job satisfaction on record.    

It’s also important to remind people that Biden really does deserve credit for the recovery package. He pushed it through Congress with only a couple votes to spare in the House and no room in the Senate.

After getting the recovery package through, Biden managed to pass three major bills with long-term impact. First, he passed a bipartisan infrastructure bill, which allocated funding not just for traditional infrastructure, but also replacing lead pipes for drinking water, extended high-speed Internet access, and established a national charging station network for electric vehicles.

He then passed the CHIPS Act which appropriated money for research and provided subsidies for building cutting edge semiconductors in the United States. The case for reshoring manufacturing can be overstated, but it is important to ensure secure supplies of essential economic inputs, and semiconductors certainly fit in that category.

Most importantly, Biden got the Inflation Reduction Act (IRA) passed. This bill was primarily about kick-starting the green transition with subsidies for wind and solar energy, as well as electric vehicles.

While it is easy to say that the bill is inadequate given the size of the problem, the point is that it is a huge foot in the door. Going forward, it will not just be environmentalist-types pushing for money for the transition, it will be major businesses looking for profits. We can be fairly confident that, apart from a complete political catastrophe, we will see considerable pressure for further support for a green transition.

The IRA also included more funding for I.R.S. enforcement. This is a big deal since rich people were increasingly seeing taxes as optional. The I.R.S. now has cops on the beat to crack down on billionaire tax cheats.

Biden also pushed a pro-labor agenda, appointing people to the National Labor Relations Board who take seriously the responsibility to protect workers’ right to organize. He was also the first president ever to join a union picket line when he marched with UAW strikers last fall.

He also appointed people to the Federal Trade Commission and the Justice Department who take anti-trust policy seriously. Mergers and acquisitions that might have gone through unquestioned under prior administrations were scrutinized, and in some cases blocked.

We have seen a half-century of anti-labor policies and neglect of meaningful anti-trust enforcement. This cannot be reversed in a single four-year term, but Biden made a very good start.

I have written much on Biden’s record on domestic policy and will write more, but it was very impactful. He has much to show for three and half years in office with the barest congressional majority in the first two years and a split Congress in the second half of his term. He will be stepping down at the top of his game.

Getting back to Biden’s decision to step down, it is difficult to imagine how hard it is for these people to give up the power and status they have struggled for a lifetime to gain. To take a more pernicious example of a politician whose career in some ways paralleled Biden’s, Richard Nixon rose from a modest background to become vice-president, before narrowly losing the presidential race in 1960 to John F. Kennedy. He then lost a race for governor in California and seemed to declare the end of his political career, saying in an angry press conference “you won’t have Dick Nixon to kick around anymore.”

Remarkably, he came back to get the Republican nomination and then slip into the White House in 1968 in another close election. Being obsessed with power, he spied on his opponents and engaged in various types of illegal activity to contain opposition. (The current SCOTUS would probably say it was all legal.)

Anyhow, things began to unravel for Nixon when the Watergate break-in was uncovered and then people began to talk. The line got traced back to the White House and the key evidence was to be found on Nixon’s own tapes. When the Supreme Court ordered them released and the public saw them, it was clear that Nixon was in on the coverup from the beginning and everything he had said about the case was a lie.

In spite of this, Nixon was prepared to tough it out. The Republicans in Congress realized this was a disaster for the party. They sent a delegation of three senior senators to see Nixon, led by Barry Goldwater, the 1964 nominee and godfather of the modern conservative movement.

They told Nixon the score, trying politely to urge him to step down. Since Nixon’s impeachment in the House was already a foregone conclusion, he began to inquire about whether he could get the one-third of the Senate needed to keep him in office.

According to their account, Nixon turned to them and said something to the effect of “let’s see, I have you three” and then started to come up with other potential names. Goldwater shut this down by telling Nixon that he didn’t know that he could count on him. Nixon resigned the next day.

Anyhow, President Biden obviously cares far more about the country and the party, but the Nixon episode shows how hard it can be for people to step aside once they have attained the pinnacle of power. We really do owe him a big debt of gratitude.

I will add one more point to put this in context. Can anyone imagine Donald Trump doing the same thing?  

The Washington Post published a scorecard that evaluated the economy’s performance during the Trump and Biden administrations. While it has much useful information, there are a few areas where it needs some additional clarification.

The first and most important issue is the comparison of real wage growth under Trump and Biden. The problem is that the Post chart uses the average hourly real wage in January 2021, when Trump left office, as the basis for the comparisons.

This is problematic since the wage for that month is hugely distorted by the fact millions of low-paid workers were still unemployed as a result of the pandemic. For example, employment in the low-paying leisure and hospitality sector was 4.1 million lower in January 2021 than it had been in February 2020 before the pandemic hit. This has the effect of raising the average wage in the same way that getting rid of the shortest person in the room increases the average height.

We are interested in the change in real wages that workers actually see, not increases due to changes in the composition of the workforce. There is no perfect way to adjust for this composition issue, but a crude correction would be to treat February 2020 as the endpoint for the Trump years and the start point for the Biden years. This treatment would also be consistent with some of the other graphs, where the pandemic period is pulled out and not attributed to either president.

With this adjustment, the growth in the average real wage for production and nonsupervisory workers during the Trump years was 3.6 percent compared to 3.1 percent in the Biden years. That compares to the growth shown in the Post chart of 7.6 percent in the Trump years and 0.2 percent in the Biden years.

Home Buying

Another area that deserves some comment is its treatment of home buying. The piece compares the monthly cost of buying the median house, relative to median income, under Trump and Biden. This cost was far lower under Trump than Biden primarily because mortgage rates were far lower but also because there was a sharp rise in house prices in the first year of the Biden administration.

While this comparison is accurate, it is primarily relevant for potential first-time homebuyers. That is a relatively small group compared to the 86 million households who already own a home.

This group hugely benefitted by the low interest rates from the start of the pandemic until the Fed began raising rates in March 2022. More than 14 million people refinanced their mortgages at lower interest rates. On average, these households are saving more than $2,000 a year on interest payments.

It is also worth noting that, while the run-up in house prices is an unambiguous negative from the standpoint of first-time buyers, it can be a positive for existing homeowners. Higher house prices will help them if they move to a lower-cost area, downsize, become renters, or opt to get a reverse mortgage to help support their retirement.

Employment to Population Ratios

The piece includes a section showing overall employment to population ratios (EPOP), as well as the ratios for Black and women workers. This sort of comparison is distorted by the fact that the huge baby boom cohort is moving into its 60s and 70s, ages where they are far more likely to be retired.

A better comparison would look at the EPOPs for prime-age workers, ages 25 to 54. By this measure, the Biden administration looks considerably better than the Trump administration. For 2023, the year-round average for the overall prime-age EPOP was 80.7 percent, compared to just 80.0 percent in 2019, the best year under Trump.

For prime-age women workers the year-round average EPOP was 75.1 percent in 2023 compared to 73.7 percent in 2019. For prime-age Black workers the year-round average was 77.6 percent in 2023, 1.6 percentage points higher than the 2019 peak of 76.0 percent under Trump.

There is much useful material in the Post’s charts, but these are areas where some additional context would have been helpful.

The Washington Post published a scorecard that evaluated the economy’s performance during the Trump and Biden administrations. While it has much useful information, there are a few areas where it needs some additional clarification.

The first and most important issue is the comparison of real wage growth under Trump and Biden. The problem is that the Post chart uses the average hourly real wage in January 2021, when Trump left office, as the basis for the comparisons.

This is problematic since the wage for that month is hugely distorted by the fact millions of low-paid workers were still unemployed as a result of the pandemic. For example, employment in the low-paying leisure and hospitality sector was 4.1 million lower in January 2021 than it had been in February 2020 before the pandemic hit. This has the effect of raising the average wage in the same way that getting rid of the shortest person in the room increases the average height.

We are interested in the change in real wages that workers actually see, not increases due to changes in the composition of the workforce. There is no perfect way to adjust for this composition issue, but a crude correction would be to treat February 2020 as the endpoint for the Trump years and the start point for the Biden years. This treatment would also be consistent with some of the other graphs, where the pandemic period is pulled out and not attributed to either president.

With this adjustment, the growth in the average real wage for production and nonsupervisory workers during the Trump years was 3.6 percent compared to 3.1 percent in the Biden years. That compares to the growth shown in the Post chart of 7.6 percent in the Trump years and 0.2 percent in the Biden years.

Home Buying

Another area that deserves some comment is its treatment of home buying. The piece compares the monthly cost of buying the median house, relative to median income, under Trump and Biden. This cost was far lower under Trump than Biden primarily because mortgage rates were far lower but also because there was a sharp rise in house prices in the first year of the Biden administration.

While this comparison is accurate, it is primarily relevant for potential first-time homebuyers. That is a relatively small group compared to the 86 million households who already own a home.

This group hugely benefitted by the low interest rates from the start of the pandemic until the Fed began raising rates in March 2022. More than 14 million people refinanced their mortgages at lower interest rates. On average, these households are saving more than $2,000 a year on interest payments.

It is also worth noting that, while the run-up in house prices is an unambiguous negative from the standpoint of first-time buyers, it can be a positive for existing homeowners. Higher house prices will help them if they move to a lower-cost area, downsize, become renters, or opt to get a reverse mortgage to help support their retirement.

Employment to Population Ratios

The piece includes a section showing overall employment to population ratios (EPOP), as well as the ratios for Black and women workers. This sort of comparison is distorted by the fact that the huge baby boom cohort is moving into its 60s and 70s, ages where they are far more likely to be retired.

A better comparison would look at the EPOPs for prime-age workers, ages 25 to 54. By this measure, the Biden administration looks considerably better than the Trump administration. For 2023, the year-round average for the overall prime-age EPOP was 80.7 percent, compared to just 80.0 percent in 2019, the best year under Trump.

For prime-age women workers the year-round average EPOP was 75.1 percent in 2023 compared to 73.7 percent in 2019. For prime-age Black workers the year-round average was 77.6 percent in 2023, 1.6 percentage points higher than the 2019 peak of 76.0 percent under Trump.

There is much useful material in the Post’s charts, but these are areas where some additional context would have been helpful.

Leading media outlets like The New York Times, The Atlantic, and The New Yorker have about as much concern for intellectual consistency as TikTok videos. In very serious and somber tones they will warn the rest of us about a major problem and then in the next issue, or the next article, present a story that is 180 degrees at odds without ever realizing the contradiction.

My favorite example of this “Which way is up?” problem is the simultaneous concern expressed that AI will eliminate all the jobs and that declining birth rates will lead to worker shortages. We got a taste of the former in an NYT article about efforts by OpenAI’s CEO Sam Altman to promote guaranteed income programs.

According to the piece, Altman and other tech types who share his views, are concerned that AI will lead to mass unemployment and further increase the gap between rich and poor. While this concern is voiced frequently in elite publications it is 180 degrees at odds with almost everything else they write.

First and foremost, if AI is going to lead to massive job loss there is zero reason to worry that declining birth rates will lead to a shrinking workforce. If we don’t have any jobs, why would we need more workers?

This issue also comes up with immigration. We are regularly told that we need immigrants because we have a shortage of native-born workers. But if AI is going to eliminate all the jobs, we won’t need large-scale immigration. To be clear, there are other reasons we might want immigration, but we can’t believe both. AI will lead to a massive loss of jobs and we also need immigrants to do our work.

The idea that AI will lead to massive job loss also means that productivity growth, and therefore economic growth, will be far more rapid than current projections indicate. The latest projections from the Congressional Budget Office show productivity growth averaging a bit over 1.6 percent annually over the next decade.

It’s not clear how fast the AI-will-kill-all-the-jobs gang expect productivity to grow, but we had productivity growth averaging just under 3.0 percent annually from 1947 to 1973, and we still maintained low rates of unemployment through most of this period. Clearly, they must envision considerably faster productivity growth, perhaps 5 or 6 percent annually.

If we had productivity growth anywhere near this fast, many other widely hyped concerns would quickly disappear. For example, the widely touted national debt would look pretty inconsequential if we could sustain anywhere near 5.0 percent productivity growth over a decade. (That would be the case even with 3.0 percent productivity growth.)

Also, the projected shortfalls in Social Security would be eliminated if average wages rose anywhere near as fast as productivity, as has largely been the case in the past. (It’s true that the median wage has not kept pace with productivity growth, but that is mostly due to the upward redistribution of wealth to highly paid workers like CEOs, Wall Street types, and well-placed STEM workers, not a failure of average wages to keep pace with productivity.)

We also would have little reason to be concerned about inflation if we’re seeing the sort of extraordinary productivity gains anticipated by the AI proselytizers. As a first approximation, inflation is equal to wage growth minus productivity growth. If we have productivity growth of 5.0 percent annually, we can have 7.0 percent nominal wage growth and still be at the Fed’s 2.0 percent inflation target. That pace would be more rapid than the peaks we saw in 2021–2022 when we were bouncing back from the pandemic.

In short, if the worldview being hyped by the AI folks in this piece is anywhere close to accurate, many of the concerns expressed in public discussions are completely off the mark. Either the AI gang is wrong or many other people writing in elite publications are wasting their time.

Is There a Case for a Guaranteed Income?

Since people often ask me, I might as well throw in a few words. I find the basic question sort of silly since it rarely is posed in the real-world context of being a question of trade-offs. (This is assuming that the AI gang is wrong in thinking that AI will take all the jobs.) Like many people, I would say that abstractly a guaranteed income would be a good idea, but in a world where millions of parents can’t afford child care, and many have inadequate housing and health care, I would have a hard time arguing that a guaranteed income should be a top priority.

A guaranteed income makes more sense in countries that have more fully developed welfare states. But $1,000 a month, or whatever is picked as the income target, will not pay for people’s health care, food, housing, and their kids’ child care. I would place the priority on ensuring that everyone has access to these necessities.

I’ll also add my other standard line. The massive inequality we see in America today is not simply due to market outcomes, rather it is the result of how we have chosen to structure the market.

The most important issue here is government-granted patent and copyright monopolies. These redistribute over $1 trillion a year from the rest of us to people in a position to benefit from these government-granted monopolies. This is seen most clearly with people like Bill Gates, who might still be working for a living if he couldn’t count on the government arresting people who used Microsoft’s software without his permission. While it is possible to argue for the merits of patent and copyright laws as policies for promoting innovation and creative work, the point is that they are policies, not intrinsic features of the market.

I realize that people who write for elite outlets don’t like to acknowledge the fact that inequality is the result of how we have chosen to structure the market, not the result of the natural workings of the market. This allows them to pontificate about how the winners should best toss a few breadcrumbs to the losers, as the AI gang seems to be doing. It avoids the question of whether we should not have rigged the market in a way to produce such extreme inequality in the first place. (Yes, this is my book, Rigged [it’s free].)

Leading media outlets like The New York Times, The Atlantic, and The New Yorker have about as much concern for intellectual consistency as TikTok videos. In very serious and somber tones they will warn the rest of us about a major problem and then in the next issue, or the next article, present a story that is 180 degrees at odds without ever realizing the contradiction.

My favorite example of this “Which way is up?” problem is the simultaneous concern expressed that AI will eliminate all the jobs and that declining birth rates will lead to worker shortages. We got a taste of the former in an NYT article about efforts by OpenAI’s CEO Sam Altman to promote guaranteed income programs.

According to the piece, Altman and other tech types who share his views, are concerned that AI will lead to mass unemployment and further increase the gap between rich and poor. While this concern is voiced frequently in elite publications it is 180 degrees at odds with almost everything else they write.

First and foremost, if AI is going to lead to massive job loss there is zero reason to worry that declining birth rates will lead to a shrinking workforce. If we don’t have any jobs, why would we need more workers?

This issue also comes up with immigration. We are regularly told that we need immigrants because we have a shortage of native-born workers. But if AI is going to eliminate all the jobs, we won’t need large-scale immigration. To be clear, there are other reasons we might want immigration, but we can’t believe both. AI will lead to a massive loss of jobs and we also need immigrants to do our work.

The idea that AI will lead to massive job loss also means that productivity growth, and therefore economic growth, will be far more rapid than current projections indicate. The latest projections from the Congressional Budget Office show productivity growth averaging a bit over 1.6 percent annually over the next decade.

It’s not clear how fast the AI-will-kill-all-the-jobs gang expect productivity to grow, but we had productivity growth averaging just under 3.0 percent annually from 1947 to 1973, and we still maintained low rates of unemployment through most of this period. Clearly, they must envision considerably faster productivity growth, perhaps 5 or 6 percent annually.

If we had productivity growth anywhere near this fast, many other widely hyped concerns would quickly disappear. For example, the widely touted national debt would look pretty inconsequential if we could sustain anywhere near 5.0 percent productivity growth over a decade. (That would be the case even with 3.0 percent productivity growth.)

Also, the projected shortfalls in Social Security would be eliminated if average wages rose anywhere near as fast as productivity, as has largely been the case in the past. (It’s true that the median wage has not kept pace with productivity growth, but that is mostly due to the upward redistribution of wealth to highly paid workers like CEOs, Wall Street types, and well-placed STEM workers, not a failure of average wages to keep pace with productivity.)

We also would have little reason to be concerned about inflation if we’re seeing the sort of extraordinary productivity gains anticipated by the AI proselytizers. As a first approximation, inflation is equal to wage growth minus productivity growth. If we have productivity growth of 5.0 percent annually, we can have 7.0 percent nominal wage growth and still be at the Fed’s 2.0 percent inflation target. That pace would be more rapid than the peaks we saw in 2021–2022 when we were bouncing back from the pandemic.

In short, if the worldview being hyped by the AI folks in this piece is anywhere close to accurate, many of the concerns expressed in public discussions are completely off the mark. Either the AI gang is wrong or many other people writing in elite publications are wasting their time.

Is There a Case for a Guaranteed Income?

Since people often ask me, I might as well throw in a few words. I find the basic question sort of silly since it rarely is posed in the real-world context of being a question of trade-offs. (This is assuming that the AI gang is wrong in thinking that AI will take all the jobs.) Like many people, I would say that abstractly a guaranteed income would be a good idea, but in a world where millions of parents can’t afford child care, and many have inadequate housing and health care, I would have a hard time arguing that a guaranteed income should be a top priority.

A guaranteed income makes more sense in countries that have more fully developed welfare states. But $1,000 a month, or whatever is picked as the income target, will not pay for people’s health care, food, housing, and their kids’ child care. I would place the priority on ensuring that everyone has access to these necessities.

I’ll also add my other standard line. The massive inequality we see in America today is not simply due to market outcomes, rather it is the result of how we have chosen to structure the market.

The most important issue here is government-granted patent and copyright monopolies. These redistribute over $1 trillion a year from the rest of us to people in a position to benefit from these government-granted monopolies. This is seen most clearly with people like Bill Gates, who might still be working for a living if he couldn’t count on the government arresting people who used Microsoft’s software without his permission. While it is possible to argue for the merits of patent and copyright laws as policies for promoting innovation and creative work, the point is that they are policies, not intrinsic features of the market.

I realize that people who write for elite outlets don’t like to acknowledge the fact that inequality is the result of how we have chosen to structure the market, not the result of the natural workings of the market. This allows them to pontificate about how the winners should best toss a few breadcrumbs to the losers, as the AI gang seems to be doing. It avoids the question of whether we should not have rigged the market in a way to produce such extreme inequality in the first place. (Yes, this is my book, Rigged [it’s free].)

That is a question that should occur to people who read through the Republican Party’s platform. Not only does the platform promise to extend the 2017 tax cuts, which will potentially put tens of billions of dollars in Elon Musk’s pocket over the next decade, it also promises to “modernize the military.”

“Republicans will ensure our Military is the most modern, lethal and powerful Force in the World. We will invest in cutting- edge research and advanced technologies, including an Iron Dome Missile Defense Shield, support our Troops with higher pay, and get woke Leftwing Democrats fired as soon as possible.”

This looks to be hundreds of billions or even trillions of dollars in additional spending over the next decade. Elon Musk, among others, is likely to be well-situated to get some of the contracts that will be involved in modernizing the military.

It is also important to understand the prospect of a massive increase in military spending in its larger context. We currently are spending roughly $900 billion a year on the military, or a bit more than 3.0 percent of GDP. If we were to expand to the Cold War levels we saw under Reagan, that would take us to $1.8 trillion a year or 6.0 percent of GDP.

In this respect, it is worth noting that the Soviet Union’s economy at its peak was roughly 60 percent of the size of the U.S. economy. China’s economy is already almost 25 percent larger than the U.S. economy and growing considerably more rapidly. This means that if we are getting into a full-fledged arms race, the 1980s Cold War spending may be too conservative.

As far as how much Musk and other military contractors are likely to get out of an increase in spending, it is worth noting that excessive payments and outright fraud are already big problems with military contracting. However, the problem is likely to get considerably worse in a second Trump administration.

There are a number of potential checks on fraud and abuse in place at present. These include the Defense Department’s Inspector General, the Government Accountability Office (GAO), and the Justice Department, which can investigate allegations of fraud.

Donald Trump has said that he wants to remove these sorts of checks on his presidential power. They would all fit into his category of the “deep state.” These people are likely the “woke Leftwing Democrats” who the platform promises to fire as soon as possible.[1]

Trump also has complete authority to direct the Justice Department to ignore allegations of fraud in military contracts. The recent Supreme Court ruling on presidential immunity even stated that a prosecutor could not ask questions as to whether a payment to Trump or his family members, AKA “a bribe”, was a factor in the awarding of a contract. This means there could be quite a windfall in an expanded military budget for well-positioned contractors. (Elon Musk just promised to contribute hundreds of millions of dollars to Trump’s election campaign.)

Matt Yglesias has made a similar point about Trump’s proposal for massive taxes on imports, AKA “tariffs.” Trump would have complete control over the size of these taxes and could increase or decrease them on a whim. This means that if the CEO of a company angered him with a public comment, Trump could hugely increase the taxes imposed on an essential import for this company.

Alternatively, if the CEO were to make a large contribution to Trump’s political action committee or his pocket, Trump could lower the taxes imposed on the company’s imports. And remember, the Supreme Court says no one can ask any questions about Trump’s motives for these actions.

The long and short here is that we always have to worry about corruption in government dealings, however Trump is campaigning on a platform where he is explicitly committed to removing all the potential checks and the Supreme Court has just granted him complete immunity to be as corrupt as he feels like being.

In this context, Elon Musk’s campaign contributions look like to be a very good investment, and very costly for the rest of us.

[1] GAO is a congressional agency, but it is likely that with a Republican trifecta, Congressional leaders would respond to orders from Trump to fire any GAO investigators that were raising questions about contracts he awarded.  

That is a question that should occur to people who read through the Republican Party’s platform. Not only does the platform promise to extend the 2017 tax cuts, which will potentially put tens of billions of dollars in Elon Musk’s pocket over the next decade, it also promises to “modernize the military.”

“Republicans will ensure our Military is the most modern, lethal and powerful Force in the World. We will invest in cutting- edge research and advanced technologies, including an Iron Dome Missile Defense Shield, support our Troops with higher pay, and get woke Leftwing Democrats fired as soon as possible.”

This looks to be hundreds of billions or even trillions of dollars in additional spending over the next decade. Elon Musk, among others, is likely to be well-situated to get some of the contracts that will be involved in modernizing the military.

It is also important to understand the prospect of a massive increase in military spending in its larger context. We currently are spending roughly $900 billion a year on the military, or a bit more than 3.0 percent of GDP. If we were to expand to the Cold War levels we saw under Reagan, that would take us to $1.8 trillion a year or 6.0 percent of GDP.

In this respect, it is worth noting that the Soviet Union’s economy at its peak was roughly 60 percent of the size of the U.S. economy. China’s economy is already almost 25 percent larger than the U.S. economy and growing considerably more rapidly. This means that if we are getting into a full-fledged arms race, the 1980s Cold War spending may be too conservative.

As far as how much Musk and other military contractors are likely to get out of an increase in spending, it is worth noting that excessive payments and outright fraud are already big problems with military contracting. However, the problem is likely to get considerably worse in a second Trump administration.

There are a number of potential checks on fraud and abuse in place at present. These include the Defense Department’s Inspector General, the Government Accountability Office (GAO), and the Justice Department, which can investigate allegations of fraud.

Donald Trump has said that he wants to remove these sorts of checks on his presidential power. They would all fit into his category of the “deep state.” These people are likely the “woke Leftwing Democrats” who the platform promises to fire as soon as possible.[1]

Trump also has complete authority to direct the Justice Department to ignore allegations of fraud in military contracts. The recent Supreme Court ruling on presidential immunity even stated that a prosecutor could not ask questions as to whether a payment to Trump or his family members, AKA “a bribe”, was a factor in the awarding of a contract. This means there could be quite a windfall in an expanded military budget for well-positioned contractors. (Elon Musk just promised to contribute hundreds of millions of dollars to Trump’s election campaign.)

Matt Yglesias has made a similar point about Trump’s proposal for massive taxes on imports, AKA “tariffs.” Trump would have complete control over the size of these taxes and could increase or decrease them on a whim. This means that if the CEO of a company angered him with a public comment, Trump could hugely increase the taxes imposed on an essential import for this company.

Alternatively, if the CEO were to make a large contribution to Trump’s political action committee or his pocket, Trump could lower the taxes imposed on the company’s imports. And remember, the Supreme Court says no one can ask any questions about Trump’s motives for these actions.

The long and short here is that we always have to worry about corruption in government dealings, however Trump is campaigning on a platform where he is explicitly committed to removing all the potential checks and the Supreme Court has just granted him complete immunity to be as corrupt as he feels like being.

In this context, Elon Musk’s campaign contributions look like to be a very good investment, and very costly for the rest of us.

[1] GAO is a congressional agency, but it is likely that with a Republican trifecta, Congressional leaders would respond to orders from Trump to fire any GAO investigators that were raising questions about contracts he awarded.  

Want to search in the archives?

¿Quieres buscar en los archivos?

Click Here Haga clic aquí